A World without Negative Gearing

In a surprising political move, the Labor party has outlined the reforms to negative gearing they would implement if they are the elected government.  gearing negative

The policy involves removing the ability to negatively gear established investment properties from the 1 July 2017. 

At this time, anyone already holding a negatively geared property may continue to do so.

This is known as ‘grandfathering’.

Anyone wishing to negatively gear after 1 July 2017 would have to buy new properties to do so.

In response, the Turnbull government indicated they may leave the tax parameters untouched, but it is not entirely clear what the government’s stance on negative gearing is.

Several barriers exist for the reformation of negative gearing.

Firstly, Labor would have to be elected.

Running on the basis of changes to negative gearing may not be popular.

ABS data reveals that two thirds of Australian households either own property outright, or are in the process of paying it off.

With reforms to negative gearing potentially lowering dwelling prices, capital gains and equity in the family home may be threatened for many, making it an unpopular decision.

Secondly, negative gearing has been increasingly influential in encouraging investment in property, increasing property values and generating large revenues for the real estate and construction sectors.

Over the year to June 2015, construction revenues grew a significant 13%, and real estate services grew 9%.

These were the largest increases of any sector in New South Wales, contributing to almost 30% of growth in the NSW economy.

This is not to say that the real estate services and the construction of houses are the most sustainable or productive ways to boost national economic growth.

Sydney’s property market appears to be coming into a downswing in its current cycle, which will make it very difficult for these sectors to maintain the same levels of revenue and employment as in the last few years.

The peak and potential downswing in the Sydney house and unit growth cycles are shown in Graph 1.

Growth in the current cycle appears to have peaked in late 2015, with growth rates beginning to come down sharply since this time.

Graph 1: Historical Capital Growth Rates, Sydney 

G1_Hisotical Growth Cycles, Sydney

Source: Residex

Negative gearing also presents an increasing constraint to the government budget.

According to Australian Taxation Office data, there were approximately 1.26 million landlords negatively gearing in the 2012-13 financial year.

These investors claimed over $12 billion in losses in that financial year.

Academics and economists have argued that negative gearing contributes to unaffordable house prices, along with capital gains concessions and high levels of finance relative to other assets.

As arguments for housing affordability become more salient, policies like Shorten gains popularity.

Thus it is well worth considering what consequences (intended and unintended) the policy would have on Australia’s housing markets.

This is difficult to do, because a counterfactual does not exist.

A ‘counterfactual’ is a scenario where the thing you are measuring does not exist.

If you think about it like a science experiment, we do not have a ‘control group’.

Housing markets have performed with negative gearing in place, as we know it today, for over 30 years. canberra politics ACT australia government leader

The only thing near a counterfactual available, one consistently referred to by journalists, was the brief period between the July 1985 and September 1987 where negative gearing was temporarily quarantined.

I was not alive at this time, so I do not know the Hawke-Keating policy intimately, but there are several reasons I do not think it is an appropriate indication of what may happen if Shorten’s proposal comes into play.

As with the Labor proposal, the Hawke-Keating government ‘grandfathered’ negative gearing in houses.

Unlike the current Labor model, rental losses could still be deducted, but only from income that was made on property.

Losses in one year could be deducted from the income received on property in another year.

This was applied to both established and new property, but only on new purchases.

Graph 2 shows the capital growth rates in houses during this time in Sydney, Melbourne and Brisbane, as indicated by the shaded area.

Graph 2: Historical Capital Growth Rates: Sydney, Melbourne, Brisbane 

G2_ Historical Capital Growth versus Negative Gearing

Source: Residex

There does not appear to be any causal relationship between changes to negative gearing and capital growth movements in this graph.

While it is true that growth rates here are subdued, the market was also in a cyclical downswing at this time.

Should we take this to mean that dwelling prices would not be affected by changes is negative gearing?

Consider the difference in this period in Australia’s housing markets: it is likely that there were a lot fewer investment properties in 1985-87 than there are today, as the purchase of investment properties has increased in Australia over the last three decades.

This is partly because the ability to negatively gear rental properties against salaries and wages was only introduced six months before it was temporarily repealed in 1985, and it was not until the mid-1990’s that individuals could leverage their property to buy more property without having to come up with any other deposit.

These changing frameworks made it easier to buy investment properties over time.

This means that phasing out negative gearing today is not the same as it was in 1985.

A paper modelling the tax benefits of the opposition’s proposal was released in February 2016 by Associate Professor at the Australian National University, Ben Phillips. australia house property map real estate aus state country

The paper was aimed at understanding the tax revenue that could be made in the long run from reforming negative gearing.

It was estimated to be between $3.4-3.9 billion per year.

However, the research note on Professor Phillips’ modelling does not attempt to model behavioural changes of investors.

He did not set himself that task.

Behavioural changes in response to changing policy can lead to unintended consequences.

Theoretically, tax revenues will go up if you start charging investors more tax, but this assumes your investors won’t divest from property or they will keep buying property at the same rate.

In the lead up to grandfathered reforms, there could be an effort to purchase established properties to negatively gear before July 2017.

It could create a kind of ‘happy hour’ in the housing markets.

After July 1 2017, the inability to negatively gear existing stock might mean that a new cost-benefit analysis would go into the purchase of existing stock.

Unless an investor can positively gear a property, or they believe the capital gains will offset the costs of an investment property, they will not buy it.

This could drive prices down.

If prices are driven down, and I cannot say for sure that they would be, but if they were, this would present opportunities for people who wish to buy a family home.

However, it could also threaten the capital gains of those relying on their investment properties for later in life.

It also creates risk for those with large mortgages if they are not able to make repayments.

In any case, more modelling needs to be done on the potential behavioural reactions to reforms to negative gearing.

Want more of this type of information?

Eliza Owen


Eliza Owen is the Market Analyst for www.Onthehouse.com.au

'A World without Negative Gearing' have 5 comments

  1. March 1, 2016 @ 6:32 am Dean

    I don’t understand why anyone would rush to buy a property before the July 2017 deadline to lock in a grand fathering agreement know that in the future when they go to sell that grand fathered agreement will not be passed on to the next purchaser. So at the time of purchase they will competing against owner occupiers AND investors but at the time of sale they would likely only be selling to owner occupiers as the properties will be exempt from negative gearing…. I don’t see how they would get any decent Capitol gain when they are competing against the whole market at the time of purchase but only have about half of the market competing for the property at the time of sale.

    Also I don’t know why a bank would lend to somebody to buy a property under these circumstances when they too know that the purchaser will be selling the property in a much less competitive market than the one they purchased it in.


  2. March 1, 2016 @ 7:23 am Hamish

    If (and its a if if) such changes were implemented and housing prices fell – has the drop in stamp duty been considered?


    • March 1, 2016 @ 7:34 am Michael Yardney

      That’s a great point Hamish


    • March 1, 2016 @ 9:04 am Dean

      Very good point. Along with the drop in land tax for governments.


Would you like to share your thoughts?

Your email address will not be published.



Michael's Daily Insights

Join Michael Yardney's inner circle of daily subscribers.

NOTE: this daily service is a different subscription to our weekly newsletter so...